Thinking, Fast and Slow

by

Daniel Kahneman

Thinking, Fast and Slow: Part 4, Chapter 28 Summary & Analysis

Summary
Analysis
Loss aversion has a biological and psychological root in which negativity dominates positivity. Kahneman shows pictures of two sets of eyes—one wide and frightened, the other calmer. We are drawn to the first set because the brain contains a mechanism that gives priority to bad news. The brain responds even to symbolic threats: words like “war” and “crime” attract more attention than “peace” and “love.” Loss aversion is part of a broad negativity dominance: bad information has more impact and is processed more thoroughly. Bad impressions and bad stereotypes are quicker to from than good ones.
Loss aversion and prospect theory is thus shown to stem from System 1 processing. System 1 is an emotionally-driven type of processing and pain is a particularly visceral emotion. Thus, we try to avoid it as much as we can, along with other negative emotions and ideas.
Themes
Intuition, Deliberation, and Laziness Theme Icon
Choices, Losses, and Gains Theme Icon
The aversion to failure to reach a goal is much stronger than the desire to exceed it. Golf provides a good example of this. Each hole has a par—a number of strokes associated with it. A birdie (one stroke under par) is a gain, and a bogey (one stroke over par) is a loss. The difference in the rate of success when going for par or for a birdie was 3.6%. For a player like Tiger Woods, this would improve his average tournament score by one stroke and his earnings by almost $1 million per season.
The example of Tiger Woods expands the realm of loss aversion even further, into our unconscious behavior. Even though certainly athletes do not try to avoid losses more than they try to earn gains, the 3.6% statistic is a significant one, and demonstrates the power of not wanting to lose (even more than wanting to win).
Themes
Intuition, Deliberation, and Laziness Theme Icon
Choices, Losses, and Gains Theme Icon
Loss aversion shows up in negotiations, and particularly in renegotiations of an existing contract. It creates an asymmetry that makes agreements difficult to reach: concessions that you make are gains for me, but losses for you. They will cause you more pain than pleasure for me. Loss aversion thus favors minimal changes from the status quo.
Like the example of Albert and Ben and their leisure time, negotiations tend to maintain the status quo because of the loss aversion principle: one party will always feel the outcome more painfully than the other.
Themes
Choices, Losses, and Gains Theme Icon
Thaler, Knetsch, and Kahneman next designed a survey to examine people’s view of fairness in economic transactions. One question described a hardware store that sells snow shovels for $15, but the morning after a snowstorm, raises the prices to $20. Even though the store acts according to the standard economic model, 82% of people rate this action as Unfair or Very Unfair.
In evaluating corporations, people also consider the principle of loss aversion. In this example, people put themselves in the shoes of the buyers and feel entitled to the standard price of the snow shovel. This causes them to see the extra $5 as a loss. 
Themes
Choices, Losses, and Gains Theme Icon
Get the entire Thinking, Fast and Slow LitChart as a printable PDF.
Thinking, Fast and Slow PDF
In another example (written in 1984), people viewed it as unfair if a small shop reduced the wage of its only employee from $9 to $7 an hour, even if other competitive shops hired workers at the lower rate. But people did not consider it unfair if the current employee left and the shop hired a new employee at $7 an hour. People do not like firms that exploit their power and believe that the first employee is entitled to a given rate, but also understand that the firm wants to maintain its current profit. Employers who violate rules of fairness are punished by loss of both productivity and sales.
Similar to the example with the snow shovel, people place themselves in the shoes of the worker. They feel like the company acts unfairly in the first instance and not in the second; the difference is that in the first case, the worker experiences a painfully felt loss. In the second, the worker experiences no such loss, and thus they do not feel like the company acts unfairly.
Themes
Choices, Losses, and Gains Theme Icon
The influence of loss aversion and entitlements extends into justice. A merchant whose goods were lost in transit may be compensated for costs (which people view as losses) but is unlikely to be compensated for lost profits (which people view as foregone gains).
Again, when considering the plight of others, people inherently operate under the concept of loss aversion: the loss of goods is viewed as a change in wealth, but the profits were never made, and therefore not experienced as a loss.
Themes
Choices, Losses, and Gains Theme Icon